MEANING OF MICROECONOMICS
Microeconomics
is a ‘bottom-up’
approach. It is a study in economics which involves everyday life, including
what we see and experience. It studies individual behavioral patterns, that of
households and corporate, their policies, how they respond to different stimuli
etc. Microeconomics largely studies supply and demand behaviors in different
markets that make up the economy, consumer behavior and spending patterns,
wage-price behavior, corporate policies, impact on companies due to regulations
etc.
Microeconomics
is the study of individuals, households and firms' behavior in decision making
and allocation of resources. It generally applies to markets of goods and
services and deals with individual and economic issues.
Microeconomic study deals with what choices people make, what factors influence their choices and how their decisions affect the goods markets by affecting the price, the supply and demand.
Microeconomics is a sub-unit of the
vast subject of economics. It is an essential social science subject.
Before getting into the details of it, let us discuss economics as a concept.
Microeconomics (from Greek prefix mikro-
meaning "small" + economics) is a branch of economics that
studies the behaviour of individuals and firms in making decisions regarding
the allocation of scarce resources and the interactions among these individuals
and firms.[1][2][3]
One goal of
microeconomics is to analyze the market mechanisms that establish relative
prices among goods and services and allocate limited resources among
alternative uses. Microeconomics shows conditions under which free markets lead
to desirable allocations. It also analyzes market failure, where markets fail
to produce efficient results.
Microeconomics
stands in contrast to macroeconomics, which involves "the sum total of
economic activity, dealing with the issues of growth, inflation, and
unemployment and with national policies relating to these issues".[2]
Microeconomics also deals with the effects of economic policies (such as
changing taxation levels) on microeconomic behavior and thus on the
aforementioned aspects of the economy.[4] Particularly in the wake
of the Lucas critique, much of modern macroeconomic theories has been built
upon microfoundations—i.e. based upon basic assumptions about micro-level
behavior.
Economics is the ‘queen of social
sciences’. It is one of the most influential sections of knowledge. Economics
teaches the art of economizing and behaving logically. It also focuses on
rational decision making. Although economics is ancient and well-developed over
the years, it does not have any rigid definition. All the definitions of economics
are broadly classified into 3 key groups.
- Welfare definition
- Wealth definition
- Scarcity definition
In simple words, economics is the
study of the description and analysis of the nature of economics.
There are many economic theories.
However, modern economists have laid down 2 approaches to analyze economics and
economic theories.
- Microeconomics
- Macroeconomics
This term has been derived from ‘mikros’
which is a Greek word for ‘small’ or ‘millionth part’. The
approach of microeconomics, however, is very unique. It only considers a
particular economic entity. It either emphasizes on a particular consumer, one
individual price, a single firm, one particular wage or an individual income.
This branch of economics is similar to looking at the global or national
economy under the microscope.
As Prof. Manson calls it, “Atomistic
individualistic approach”,
Prof Mac Canel says that this branch
of economics “is the study of the specific economic units and a detailed
consideration of the behaviour of these individual units”.
Unlike macroeconomics, it does not
consider the entire economy as a whole. However, it focuses on the individual
economic units that are a part of the entire economy. In simple words,
microeconomics considers the various components of the forest rather than the
entire forest as a whole.
Answers 3 fundamental questions
1.
What goods should be produced?
2.
How should they be produced?
3.
For whom should they be produced?
Focuses on 3 subject matters
1.
Commodity pricing
2.
Welfare economics
3.
Pricing of factors
PRINCIPLES OF
MICROECONOMICS
Demand,
Supply and the Supply-Demand relationship
This principle of
microeconomics drives any economy and market. We buy some item almost every
day, be it food related, medicines, electronic accessories and several others.
This is ‘demand’
(not that we are too demanding in our approach). It originates from us.
Similarly, the shopkeeper demands products from the wholesaler by observing the
demand for his/her products by us. On the other hand, the shopkeeper supplies
the products to meet our demands and the wholesaler supplies what the
shopkeeper asks. This is ‘supply.’
Secondly, we ask for a number of products else, demand a certain number of
units for each of the products we buy. The same holds for supply. These are
known as ‘Quantity
Demanded’ and ‘Quantity
Supplied’ respectively.
As the quantity
demanded exceeds the quantity supplied over a period, suppliers would either
have to increase their supply or else increase the prices of the products being
sold – they are having a shortage of stock or quantity supplied. As prices go
up, demand would ideally reduce as people may not be able to afford the same
products at elevated prices. People may still demand but in lesser numbers.
This gives time for the suppliers to get back in action and supply sufficiently
to meet the demand.
As the quantity
supplied exceeds the quantity demanded, suppliers would either have to cut down
on their supply or else decrease the prices of the products being sold – they
are having a surplus/excess stock or quantity supplied. As prices go down,
demand would obviously pick up and match the supply.
When both, quantity
supplied and demanded are optimal, i.e., match perfectly, the result achieved
is a ‘State of Equilibrium.’
When they aren’t equal, what arises is either a shortage or excess which gets
adjusted to achieve equilibrium again.
The most important
rationale behind this principle of microeconomics is ‘assuming all other factors remaining the
same/equal,’ the quantity demanded decreases as price increases and
the quantity demanded increases as price decreases (inverse relationship). All
other factors remaining the same, the quantity supplied increases as price
increases and the quantity supplied decreases as price decreases (direct
relationship).
As can be understood
from what is read above, the ‘Demand
Curve’ is negatively sloped and
‘Supply Curve’ is positively sloped (see the picture below – a
straight curve is a line!). Just plot the price-demand, price-supply
relationship and you would find out. It’s a D-I-Y (Do It Yourself) assignment!

The graph above is a
depiction of the concept of ‘Equilibrium’,
the vertical axis (Y-axis) representing ‘Quantity’ demanded and supplied
whereas the horizontal axis (X-axis) represents the ‘Price’ of the product/service.
The explanation below should make it simpler for you!
[Note: By ‘higher’
and ‘lower’ prices, we mean the price relative to the ‘Equilibrium Price’ – that
which a buyer should ideally bid/buy
for (OR) the price relative to that which a seller should ideally ask/offer.]
Substitution
and Elasticity
This is an important
principle of microeconomics. When the prices are higher relative to what one
can afford people may prefer cheaper ‘substitute
goods’ to what they generally buy – substitution effect. This behavior of change
in demand due to price is called ‘price
elasticity of demand’ – just like an elastic band which is flexible
and changes according to the shape and contours of the object. If coffee is
costlier than tea but you also like tea, you would go ahead with drinking tea
if the prices of coffee have gone up. Tea substitutes coffee in this example.
Giffen
Goods/ Giffen Paradox
Obviously named
after Mr. Giffen (Sir Robert Giffen), they are a unique category of goods. What
makes them unique is the price and demand equation. We know through principle
of microeconomics and common sense that the quantity demanded falls as the
price of that good rises. So here are a few examples for you:
- If you follow
soccer, you would be aware of the transfer of players to different clubs
every season. Often times, good players and their teams demand a higher
price for the player being sold by them. The higher the price bid, the
more valuable the player and importantly some teams are ever more willing
to buy that player even as their price increases.
- A clichéd
example – does the demand for salt get subdued because its price is on the
rise. People seem to be indifferent to the price.
Even as the price
rises, demand doesn’t lurk – Strange. In fact, demand increases as prices rise!
To think deeper, people are not really that dumb! These are probably rational
decisions, but you are absolutely willing to pay a higher price despite the
rise in prices. These types of exceptional goods are called ‘Giffen goods’ where the demand curve is positively sloped. These
goods might seem overpriced but on deeper thought, undervalued i.e., they might
increase in price but might actually be cheaper than its substitutes. These are
not to be confused with the next category of goods!
There are three
criteria which Giffen goods have to fulfil to be called such:
- A lack of
substitute goods;
- The good bought
should be an inferior good (a good where a rise in income would lead to a
fall in demand. If your income has risen, you would prefer an Uber taxi to
a bus/auto if the latter was your daily mode of transport)
- A good portion
of the consumer’s income should be used to buy the product but at the same
time, it should not be the case where consumers don’t buy regular products
which they do normally (normal goods).
Veblen
Goods
They are similar to
Giffen goods yet they are different principle of microeconomics. These are
goods which are seen as a status of esteem, luxury and something for which you
don’t mind paying a high price even as prices increase. A typical example is
that of the Rolls Royce car, jewellery, gems etc. where the higher prices are,
the greater the intensity to purchase that good to show your status such that
you end up the purchasing it. Giffen goods are not luxurious by nature like
Veblen goods.
Income
and Inelasticity in Microeconomics
Giffen and Veblen
goods are examples of ‘price
inelastic demand’. The demand doesn’t vary due to price which makes
it inelastic. There is no need to substitute your demand for that particular
good. This might be due to your elevated income levels – part of the income effect as compared
to substitution effect. The income you get to spend comes from external sources
like salaries etc. and/or a fall in the price of the good you spend on (saving
money) and/or sacrificing buying the next best product which might be costlier
than the product you currently spend on assuming you buy the best and most
beneficial product – the opportunity cost of the product.
Opportunity
Cost in Microeconomics
Here, we come to a
key principle of microeconomics – ‘Opportunity
Cost’ i.e., the cost incurred by not choosing the second best
alternative (because we assume you go for the best alternative) given that the
choices are mutually
exclusive (one choice eliminates the others). In other words, it is
the marginal benefit one could derive by choosing the second best comparable
alternative to achieve the same purpose given that the choices are mutually
exclusive. Put simply, it is an opportunity which you didn’t choose.
Example: You are a 5 year
old kid and have $5 with you to choose between an ice-cream and Swiss chocolate
which cost $5 and $4 respectively (would a 5 year old kid really care if it
were a Swiss chocolate? I doubt he’d know its specialty. Who knows?). Let’s say
that the kid chooses the chocolate over the ice-cream just to spoil our clichéd
assumption that a kid would always choose the ice-cream! He relishes the
chocolate until he sees his friend relishing the ice-cream. The kid then tries
to weigh the costs of his decision to go for the chocolate.

At
the Margin and Indifferent Preferences
Now we have to
understand why such decisions are made – looking at opportunity costs, at our
spending behaviors due to income effects, substitution effects and several such
related patterns. A good reason to explain it all apart from our intuitiveness
is that we look at everything from an incremental standpoint, a marginal
standpoint
- How much better
would I be if I made the decision of going with ‘X’ over ‘Y?
- How much more
should I spend if I go for ‘X’ than ‘Y’?
- At what point
will I be totally satisfied that I have as many units of ‘X’ over ‘Y’?
- When will I
attain a state of mind where I’m fine with both ‘X’ and ‘Y’ such that both
satisfy me equally? At what point will I stop being choosy about both?
Some questions are
logical and some are philosophical. Sounds interesting right?
This is where the
concepts of Marginal Utility and Marginal Costs kick in!
Marginal utility
being the additional benefit you derive by consuming a good/service over
another and marginal cost being the extra cost incurred/price paid by consuming
that good/service in simple terms.
Indifference
Curves – Microeconomics
Till now, we have
covered a lot of principle of microeconomics in an intuitive way, through
common sense and different examples. What governs a horde of the above concepts
and principles comes from the study of the famous ‘Indifference Curves.’ Bear with me!!
Refer to the
Indifference Points – Microeconomics for an example.

The curve joining the points PAQ above, is from the set of sample data points’ in the Excel sheet (Right Click on the Chart after inputting the sample data points – Change Series Chart Type – Scatter Plot). You would be able to connect the points PAQ through a curve.
What is going on?
Using the sample
data in the Excel sheet, you would find out that point A could be looked at
like a benchmark. Point A
would be preferred against the points on the left-bottom
(south-west) of A
and; Point A would not be preferred
to the points on the right-top
(north-east) of A. Obviously you would prefer maximum units of both
the goods and thus preferences would move along the north eastern side.
By inputting the
sample data points in the excel sheet example, we obtain the following graph
and conclusions:

- A would clearly
be preferred to B,Y and R with B being preferred the least
- Z would clearly
be preferred to A
- Points C and P
have more drinks than A but lesser food; X and Q have more food than A but
lesser drinks – we need greater information about how the customer would
choose between the above based on the money he has, tastes, reviews,
rankings etc.
The customer may
choose to be indifferent
between P, A and Q. If the three are connected through a line, we get an Indifference Curve. Given
PAQ is your indifference curve (the choices you are indifferent to), points C,
Y, R and X will not be preferred.
The indifference
curves could also be CAQ, PAX or CAX, but it can’t be all of them – indifference
curves can’t across each other. Why?
Let A be your
benchmark and PAQ, your curve. Assume CAX is also your curve where it cuts
across PAQ. Point A is indifferent to X and Q. X should be indifferent to Q if
the curves cut, but if you required more food, you would prefer Q over X. Thus
indifference curves can’t cut across each other.
The shapes of
indifference curves can indicate whether and how a customer would be willing to
alter his demands by substituting one good for the other. In the above example
where PAQ is your, he would be willing to substitute 25 units of drinks for 10
units of food (move from P to A in the graph – you would go down 25 units on
the Y-axis and go further 10 units on the X-axis) and 25 units of drinks for 30
units of food (A to Q).
In the simpler
initial curve given below, you would substitute 20 units of drinks for 10 units
of food (A to B) and so on!

This measure of
marginally compromising units of one for the other is called the Marginal Rate of Substitution –
for math savvy people, it’s the slope of the curve!
If you plot a budget
line on a graph with multiple indifference curves, the maximum benefit would be
derived where the budget line and the highest indifference curve is tangential.

The violet line
above is the budget line and the point in red is the tangent. That is where the
maximum utility would be derived. Although there is a lot more to dive into,
this should be good enough for now.
Summary
Goodness! This was
quite a lot to digest! Not only was it a beginner’s guide to concepts of what
is microeconomics and principle of microeconomics. It also had quite a few
‘do-it-yourself’ exercises like the excel sheet which you can freely configure
though it isn’t the ultimate solace to your questions.
Here are a few
questions for you to think about:
- If you’ve
understood Giffen goods, what do you think will happen if the prices of
these goods fall and why? (A part of the solution lies in the explanation)
- Can Veblen
goods be Giffen goods?
- We agree that
indifference curves cannot cut across each other. Can two indifference
curves stay/sit on top of each other?
- Do substitution
effects and elasticity have to go together? Do income effects and
inelasticity have to go together? (of course I have covered the two
effects intuitively and not in great detail, but it’s worth a thought.)
FUNCTIONS OF MICROECONOMICS
- This approach of economics helps us study and
understand the practical working of the economy. The entire economy is
complex and complicated for a layman to analyze. However, microeconomics
facilitates easy comprehension of the economic system.
- It provides the required tools that enable the formulation
of various economic policies. It also provides techniques that
facilitate the easy formulation of economic strategies and economic
regulations.
- Microeconomics is of great help when it comes to studying
the conditions of economic welfare. With the help of this branch of
economics, we now understand the standard of living and the condition of
welfare of the people. We can not only study their condition of welfare
but we can also analyse the factors that determine their welfare as well.
- This branch of economics helps us understand the level
of satisfaction of the people in the economy.
- It also helps economists identify the allocation of
resources within the economy. Not only is it useful in efficiently
allocating the scarce resources to productive uses but it also helps
control the use of the allocated resources as well.
- Economic theories and economic policies are very
different. Economic theories help prove a particular hypothesis or
condition in the market (in this case, the micro market). But economic
policies help in governing the smooth functioning of the economy. Hence, economic
theories can be easily drafted and formulated with the help of this
branch of modern economics.
- Taxes are an important source of income for a country.
There have been incidents of disturbances within economies due to taxation
policies. Hence, a well-planned and a well-developed taxation policy is
crucial for an economy. Microeconomics ensures to understand the
implications and problems of taxations and formulate suitable taxation
policies.
No comments